Prices are said to be a gross estimation of the value for traded goods and services. The market price doesn’t capture the “real” value of a product or service, however. For example, a kilowatt hour produced through burning coal or by a solar panel may be equivalent in terms of price, though it involves different social and environmental costs and, in that regard, would not hold for equal “values” depending on the way it was produced. Observed prices fail to reflect true economic values, taking into account government regulations that set prices for commodities, as well as taxes, subsidies and trade restrictions that create distortions in the market. In other cases, there may be no market price at all (UNDESA, 2012).
Economists use shadow pricing to assign a monetary value to the non-marketed or “abstract” goods and services, in hopes of better reflecting their total social, economic, and environmental costs and benefits (Tinch et al., 2019). In the absence of water markets or where these markets function poorly shadow pricing is used to estimate the economic value of water (UNDESA, 2012). This is often the case in agriculture where the water charge is below the marginal value product of water and shadow pricing is utilised to conduct different types of analysis (Diao & Roe, 2000; Bierkens et al., 2019). Shadow pricing method should reflect different economic values depending on when, where, and how water occurs (van der Zaag & Savenije, 2006).